It’s October 2018 already, meaning 15 months have passed since I spoke at Clean Energy Summit 2017 and provided a forecast of sorts (for train wreck underway). Since that time I have only been able to post more about 4 of the Villains that we see at work in helping our complex energy transition run off the rails:
Villain #1 | First and foremost, I see the long-running failure of our “emperors with no clothes” as a huge (and perhaps the biggest) driver of our energy transition train wreck … |
Villain #2 | … however our political class have been aided and abetted by us, the voting public, in that we have been seemingly unable to deliver stable support for the complexities inherent in such a large transformation … |
Villain #3 | Both politicians and public alike have been pulled from both extremes by an increasingly loud shouting match that’s emerged across both extremes of the Emotion-o-meter. |
Villain #4 | With participants at all points on that scale (including us as a company, and yours truly) suffering from the yawning gap that’s emerging between required and current “Energy Literacy”. |
This week I note that the AFR National Energy Summit is running in Sydney, which follows on from All Energy last week in Melbourne – in what seems to be a conveyor belt of industry get-togethers.
I was at All Energy so can’t make the AFR Summit, but I do wonder whether there is a realistic chance that the participants will avoid falling into the trap (which seems to be affecting us increasingly) of not focusing on the “real” problems:
Too often, over recent years, I have been reminded of the “Streetlight Effect” when observing the muddle being made of various aspects of the energy transition process:
The “Streetlight Effect” is a parable about a person found searching under a streetlight for their car keys, when in reality they lost them somewhere else. In some renditions, the person is drunk – hence the alternate title of “the drunkard’s search”. For those who have not heard this before it’s discussed here, here and here (and no doubt many other places).
I’ll start this post off today by noting a couple examples of how we’ve been seen to exhibit this sort of behaviour with respect to the energy sector transition. As time permits, I’ll post separately about other examples, and link them into the table below…
Date added | Example of Villain #5 | Brief discussion |
Initial (Tue 9th Oct 2018) | Not accounting directly for a price on carbon | It’s been noted many times by many different people, so not going to expand on this in this post – the most efficient/effective way to mitigate emissions would be to have a broad-based price on carbon emissions.
Unfortunately, as a result of prior Villains, we’re left with sub-optimal policy outcome – of which the last one currently standing is the various forms of target on renewable energy penetration: Though these programs do have other benefits (not the least of which, for our Villains no1, being that they are popular with fickle villains no2 – hence some would say pragmatic), we should not lose sight of the fact that they are likely to be delivering a more expensive outcome than might have otherwise been the case. Let’s call this instance Villain 5a. |
Initial (Tue 9th Oct 2018) | Focus on changing rules, rather than addressing underlying structural issues | I’ll flag this one today and hopefully find time to return later to expand on this one.
There are a number examples we have seen over a number of years whereby various parties have seemed to avoid “the elephant in the room” whilst seeking to change market rules (or mandate behaviour) to address natural outcomes of given structural configurations. As an example of this, we have the QLD Government’s “don’t make too much money” direction to Stanwell Corporation back in June 2017 – when (as noted here a couple weeks later) it was the Government’s 3-into-2 merger that created the pre-conditions that led to the escalation in volatility in the first place. Let’s call this instance Villain 5b.
|
Added on 12th December | Increasingly there is too much focus on COST, whilst not enough focus on VALUE | Added this post here on Wednesday 12th December following the latest round of celebrations on social media about the ongoing decline in the cost of production from renewable (i.e. wind and solar PV) sources.
The obsessive focus on COST has reached (passed?) it’s use-by date. Our collective focus should have been shifted already to one of VALUE. This one is Villain 5c.
|
Tue 5th March 2019 | Obsessing about NegaWatts, and losing sight of Demand Response | Added this post here on Tuesday 5th March 2019 in conjunction with some more general thoughts here about the latest round of deliberations at the AEMC about ways to facilitate a more active and responsive demand side in the NEM.
It seems, to me, that some have lost sight of the real objective whilst focusing obsessively on NegaWatts in particular. This one is Villain 5d.
|
Soon | Another example of not focusing on the real problem | The next post about Villain 5e is coming shortly (time permitting).
|
Later | More to come… | We’ll add more examples later…
|
I’m sure that some of our readers will have encountered other examples of how Villain no5 has manifest itself in the energy sector through this transition process. Feel free to add your examples as comments below, or provide us your feedback directly/confidentially – or just give us a call!
Actually, I think the most glaring example of villain #5 is not focusing on mitigating the impacts of rising temperatures. As stated above, villains 1 thru 4 ensure that, if you believe CO2 is the primary cause, that prevention is not possible. Mitigation is therefore the only viable option and it also addresses the issue that, if CO2 is not the problem, rising temperatures are going to occur despite all of our efforts.
Paul, you mentioned carbon pricing, therefore I take that as an opportunity to mention the logical inconsistency in the IPCC position. I explain it thus:
– CAUSE: IPCC position is that carbon emissions are currently the greatest threat to humanity, a threat created by developed economies and to be solved by developed economies
– ACTION: IPCC advocates reducing carbon emissions, mostly by the following mechanisms regardless of the effect on developed economies: increase renewables, reduce meat consumption, increase electric vehicles, reduce poverty and increase equity
– LOGICAL INCONSISTENCY: if reducing emissions is the most important action for humanity, and the energy system of the western world is the largest source of emissions, the logical solution is rapid transition to nuclear power generation, globally.
Since the IPCC does not recommend rapid transition to nuclear energy (which incidentally would provide electricity to more people than renewables thus reducing poverty and increasing equity), I conclude that carbon emissions are NOT the greatest threat to humanity, and therefore carbon pricing is a purely political strategy designed to restrict developed economies.
But I agree that if our chosen politicians insist on carbon pricing then it should be like the GST but with less exceptions.
Banjo,
The bias against nuclear technology in the IPCC is changing, albeit too slowly.
Using it to legitimise the idea that mitigating greenhouse gas emissions is not a very important thing to do seems just as fallacious as the thinking you seek to identify.
Bad thinking doesn’t cure bad thinking.
For only the latest group who argue forcefully for greenhouse gas mitigation AND nuclear power, see this open letter. http://environmentalprogress.org/big-news/2018/10/25/open-letter-to-heads-of-state-of-the-g-20-from-scientists-and-scholars-on-nuclear-for-climate-change
I certainly share your frustration. I think the inclusion of those technologies, rather than causing conflict, could prove a remarkable circuit breaker in Australian energy policy.